Research
Specs For SPACs
What the Clover Class Tells Us About Keeping a SPAC Case on Track.
Following news coverage on the role of profits in driving UK inflation, including the telecoms price increases first flagged by Fideres, questions have been asked in government and beyond as to whether UK competition agencies and regulators have done enough to run an inclusive competition enforcement policy. In response, the CMA has set out how it plans to change its priorities to protect consumers from the cost-of-living crisis.
For example, the Guardian (quoting Fideres) ran an investigation into parallel (mid-contract) price increases by UK telecoms and broadband providers, while the Financial Times (again quoting Fideres), questioned the implications of this conduct for the proposed Vodafone/Three merger.
The Guardian’s findings reflected the same concerns that Fideres, had asked Ofcom to investigate in 2021, but which Ofcom choose not to examine. This is perhaps understandable given the mismatch between the need for investigations into anti-competitive conduct across the UK, and the resources available to undertake them. However, it also illustrates the pressing need to open up the scope for private actions by consumer (and worker) representatives and civil society groups against anti-competitive behaviour.
Telecoms firms have for many years complained about low rates of return in the UK. They have argued that their inability to keep up with the profit margins others were extracting from less competitive markets meant that consolidation was required for investment. However, regulators and independent economists find no reliable link between less competition and increased market investment, and we are all suffering the disastrous consequences of underinvestment by water monopolists. So, regulators have admirably done their best to block the repeated efforts to force through mergers.
When Fideres wrote to Ofcom in 2021, it appeared to us that the big mobile network operators had decided that, while mergers were not possible, “competition is for losers”, as Peter Thiel says. Instead of competing to offer better prices in the hope of winning customers, they seemed to have recognized that their interests were better served by mirroring one another’s price increases, and the introduction of terms and conditions that lock consumers into paying higher prices midway through their contract.
Industry spokesmen claimed the price hikes reflected cost increases across the market. The uncanny implication of their argument was that:
The industry also disingenuously suggested consumers could simply switch to firms offering better-value deals. In fact, none of the Big Four (or the smaller brands that they control) were offering deals without the same price ratcheting mechanism. Since these firms collectively accounted for more than 90% of the market, consumers’ options to switch to better deals were extremely limited (and they have only become more so since then).
The idea that the price ratchet was the result of synchronized, identical cost increases is hard to believe and should have merited a close look in 2021. Such an investigation might have explored whether or not this impressive foresight was achieved by some of them through serendipity (each independently reaching the same conclusion), price-fixing (agreeing amongst one another), or, by recognizing they would all make bigger profits if they chose to ignore the opportunity to increase sales by competing for customers and instead simply followed the price increases of others. It was disappointing that instead of investigating, Ofcom stood by and watched. It is however true that Ofcom, the CMA, and other competition regulators have limited resources to investigate the huge variety of potentially anti-competitive behaviour occurring in markets across the economy (the CMA has just one fifth of the staff that the Bank of England). In that context it is unsurprising that profit margins have risen over the last 43 years, that competition across the economy has deteriorated, and that large parts of the legal framework are, in practice, barely applied.
Against this backdrop the UK and EU sensibly created the opportunity for private enforcement by consumer representatives, civil society groups and small businesses to complement the efforts of under-resourced regulators. However, there remain large gaps in that regime which prevent those groups from challenging conduct that the regulators are unwilling or unable to prioritize. For example:
The CMA will presumably be drawing on the OECD’s work identifying that competition agencies’ limited resources can be prioritized to ensure that competition rules can drive inclusive growth. However, unlocking the legal and practical restrictions on private enforcement, which deny consumers and workers access to justice for anticompetitive misconduct in UK markets, would help the agencies to keep pace. Removing this bottleneck would make a huge contribution towards making sure that UK markets work for everyone.
Chris joined Fideres in 2021. Chris holds a PhD, an MA and BA in Economics from the University of East Anglia. At Fideres Chris has provided expert economic advice on class action complaints against Amazon, Facebook and Apple. He has written expert reports, developed models to quantify damages, and developed analysis of market definition and abuse of dominance (monopolisation) in digital aftermarkets and multi-sided platforms.
Before joining Fideres, Chris spent 7 years as a Competition Expert for the OECD where he led the economic thinking on antitrust in digital markets, as well the role for competition law in delivering inclusivity. He published numerous papers and led a working party of the OECD Competition Committee in developing new international standards on competitive neutrality and competitive assessment in light of the digitalisation of the economy.
Chris has advised the UK Government’s Department of Trade & Industry on the benefits of competition policy, and the UK Competition Commission (predecessor to the Competition and Markets Authority) on digital mergers, retail market investigations and competition cases. He was an advisor to the Co-operation and Competition Panel on mergers, market studies and antitrust in publicly-funded healthcare markets, and later became Director of Competition Economics at the UK Healthcare Regulator. Chris is a founding member of the Centre for Competition Policy of the University of East Anglia. He remains an associate of the Centre, a member of various advisory boards at non-profit making organisations, and peer reviews papers for the Journal of Competition Law and Economics & the Journal of Antitrust Enforcement.
What the Clover Class Tells Us About Keeping a SPAC Case on Track.
Why the status quo poses risks to competition.
Unavailable and inaccessible.
London: +44 20 3397 5160
New York: +1 646 992 8510
Rome: +39 06 8587 0405
Frankfurt: +49 61 7491 63000
Johannesburg: +27 11 568 9611
Madrid: +34 919 494 330